Last week, the Equality
and Human Rights Commission published an analysis,
by Howard Reed and me, of the impact of changes to tax and benefits on
household living standards over the entire period 2010 to 2021-22. I summarised the key results in the Guardian.
We show that these changes are highly regressive: the direct impact is to reduce the net incomes of the poorest fifth of households by about a tenth, on average, while making little or no difference to the incomes of the richest fifth.
We
also expect that the impact will be a large rise in child poverty; in
particular, we are projecting that as a result of the changes to taxes and
benefits, the proportion of children in Great Britain living in households with
less than 60% of median income (after housing costs) will rise from just over
30% to about 41% in 2021-22 (Table 1 of the Executive Summary of our report. We could have used other
definitions of child poverty – the numbers would be different but the results
would be qualitatively similar).
This
prediction – which is indeed dramatic – caught the eye of Christopher
Snowdon of
the Institute for Economic Affairs. Chris’s view is that we are being far too
pessimistic; in particular, he notes that predictions made in the early years
of the Coalition government by the IFS and others of a sharp rise in child
poverty have yet to materialise, partly because of rising employment rates and
partly because real wage growth, and hence median income growth, has been very
slow. He also notes, correctly, that the
rise we are predicting would be historically unprecedented.
Now
economists in general have come in for a lot of flak recently for getting
forecasts wrong. Much of this is in my view unfair or misconceived. Nevertheless, I strongly believe that those
of us who claim to be experts, and make predictions based on our expertise,
should be prepared to stand by those predictions; we should put our money where
our mouths are.
So I offered Chris a
bet, which he has accepted, that relative child poverty (on the definition we
model) will rise above 37%. This takes into account (in crude terms) the fact that our forecast has a fairly large margin
of error: I don’t expect it to be precisely right. In particular, as Chris rightly highlights below, all sorts of other things will happen to the economy, real wages, rents, etc. Our model is not a macroeconomic one, and is not designed to forecast those variables, which will impact the results.
In order to be meaningful, the bet has to be
large enough for us to care who wins (ie, it can’t just be a token amount), so
it’s for £1,000. This
isn’t the first time I’ve done this: my previous bet with Andrew Lilico (also for £1,000) was on the level of
inflation in 2015: he thought inflation
would rise sharply; I disagreed. I won
(unfortunately, Andrew says he’s not allowed to make any further bets with me,
although I keep on offering,
since Andrew’s predictions on the Brexit process frequently venture into the
realms of fantasy).
However,
the bet with Andrew was rather easier to define, since we were simply making
competing predictions of inflation (“unconditional forecast”). But the forecast Howard and I are making is
conditional; it’s explicitly based on the government implementing the changes
to taxes and benefits that have been legislated for or are clearly stated to be
government policy. If those changes aren’t
implemented, the forecast isn’t valid any more, and we shouldn’t be held to it.
This
raises a slight difficulty in making the bet
- of course there will be further changes in one direction or another,
but will they be large enough to mean that we should be no longer held to the
forecast and hence the bet should be invalidated? How big a U-turn – for example on the
four-year freeze to most working age benefits, which has a very large impact in
our projections – would be required? In
order to deal with this, we’ve appointed an independent arbiter – Chris Giles
of the Financial Times, who will if necessary rule on this question in due
course.
The
final result won’t be in until March 2023 (when the Households Below Average
Income statistics for 2021-22) are published. But the first indications will
come on Thursday, when the statistics for 2016-17 – the first year of the benefit freeze – are
published.
Christopher
Snowdon adds:
I am
not betting against Jonathan because his child poverty forecast is the worst
prediction ever made, only that it is the latest. I am getting tired of them.
We have had eight years of gloomy predictions about rising poverty and
spiralling inequality
from the ‘independent’ (from whom?) Institute of Fiscal Studies and the
relentlessly Eeyorish Resolution Foundation. These predictions invariably
receive more media coverage than the real figures do when they are eventually
published.
By the
time Office for National Statistics’ data exposes these predictions as being
wildly off base, people have moved on. No one seems to notice, no one takes the
blame and new predictions from the same organisations are given the same
credulous reception. As a result, millions of people - perhaps the majority -
genuinely believe that the poor have got poorer, inequality has risen, and
every measure of poverty has gone up in the age of ‘austerity’.
New
figures are published on Thursday but, as of 2015/16, the rate of child poverty is slightly lower than it was
before the 2008 crash.
This is true in absolute terms, in relative terms and regardless of whether you
measure it before or after housing costs. It also happens to be a fact that the incomes of the bottom quintile have risen more than
those of richer groups,
and income inequality is lower than it was ten years ago. None of this had made the front pages.
The
thousand pound question is will it be different this time? It is true that when
measured in relative terms, child poverty has risen since hitting a low in
2012/13 and I am less comfortable betting on relative poverty than on incomes
or ‘absolute’ poverty (the latter is actually a relative measure that uses
2010/11 as the benchmark). I am generally optimistic about people’s incomes,
but with relative poverty it is not clear what optimism implies. Relative
poverty tends to fall when the economy is doing badly and rise when it is doing
well.
If I
thought that the economy was going to be stellar in the next few years while
benefits are frozen, I would not take the bet. But I suspect that GDP and wages
will, at best, trundle gradually upwards. I don’t share the IFS’s belief that
average wages will not return to pre-crash levels until 2022, but it will take
at least a year or two.
It is,
I think, probable that the next five years will see at least two of the
following three: an unspectacular rise in median earnings, fairly low
inflation, and rising incomes for those in the bottom deciles who are employed.
The government also intends to raise the minimum wage so that it equates to 60
per cent of median earnings, meaning that nobody on the minimum wage full-time
will be in relative poverty, and the income tax threshold is due to rise
further. This all works in my favour, but it is not the main reason I accepted
the bet.
The
main reasons are threefold. Firstly, Jonathan was prepared to wager, which is
more than can be said for those who make obesity predictions. More academics and pundits should put skin in
the game. Incidentally, if any of the people who believe the NHS is going to be
privatised want to put money on it, you know where to find me.
Secondly,
while I accept that freezing benefits is likely to lead to a rise in relative
poverty, the rate being predicted is extremely high. In the last 25 years, it
has always been between 27 and 34 per cent. 41.3 per cent by 2021/22 would be
one hell of a jump and even the lower rate of 37 per cent that is the basis of
our bet would, as Jonathan says above, be unprecedented. That doesn’t make it
impossible, but an extraordinary outcome requires extraordinary policies. I’m
not convinced that May’s benefit reforms fit the bill.
Thirdly,
every previous forecast I can recall has been wrong - and wrong in the same
direction. They have all overestimated the rate of future poverty, inequality and, in the case of Danny Blanchflower, unemployment. It would be Sod’s Law if a prediction finally
came true when I have money against it, but I don’t think the earlier
predictions were wrong because of a run of bad luck. I think they suffered from
the same systemic flaw. Leaving aside the possibility that they they are
deliberately biased upwards to draw public attention to policies of which the
authors disapprove, they tend to be based on what people’s income would be if
they did not respond to economic incentives. But people change their behaviour
to maximise financial returns. One reason why incomes have risen so much in the
bottom fifth since the crash is that people have moved into the labour market -
or, if already in the labour market, have worked more hours. We now have the
lowest unemployment rate in forty years, but it could go lower.
I
haven’t read Jonathan’s report and I claim no expertise. I am just some chump
who distrusts gloomy economic forecasts. Do bear that in mind if I win the bet.
But I have to say that this is probably all academic. The most likely outcome
of this bet is that it is invalidated by a change in policy. The Tories have
developed a peculiar habit of shouting loudly about big, unpopular spending
cuts and then whispering quietly when they deliver the inevitable U-turn,
thereby ensuring the worst possible publicity for the least possible benefit to
the public finances. I expect these reforms to be watered down or ended
prematurely for political reasons, so we will probably never know if Jonathan’s
model was right.