[This blog, by NIESR Principal Research Fellow Alex Bryson, summarises the articles published in the February 2013 special issue of the National Institute Economic Review on China's economy].
China’s political
future has been settled – for the time-being – with a new cadre of political
leaders taking over nearly 3 months ago. But its economic future appears less
certain. With annual GDP growth projected to remain below 8 per cent
some commentators are revisiting debates about the sustainability of China’s
economic growth. Here we point to a
number of factors that suggest China's economy remains in pretty good shape to
face many of the new challenges it faces.
China's at the crossroads, again. With the decennial
transfer of political power comes uncertainty about the future direction of the
country. This is always the case. What
is different this time is that the last decade has been a period of economic
growth in China which is perhaps unparalleled in human history, anywhere. But there is anxiety among the political
elite and the increasingly prosperous middle classes about how sustainable the
current path is. Growth has been
slowing, albeit from a remarkably high rate, fuelling unrest among those afraid
of losing their new-found gains.
Inequality has been rising at an alarming rate. The 'have-nots' have
begun to make their voices heard, both through social media and on the ground
with industrial unrest a major problem for the regime, particularly in the
interior. Some question whether the Chinese model of "socialist
capitalism" is compatible with long-term growth, arguing that democracy is
a pre-requisite for sustainable growth. Others think the current arrangements
are more robust and that China's road to a market economy has been laid by
sound political decision-making, especially at provincial, regional and city
level where many of the policy experiments behind China's success have been
devised, piloted and implemented. Seen in this light, some of the recent
difficulties China has been facing, such as wage inflation, can be seen as part
of the typical difficulties countries face as they transit towards a market
economy. So now seems like a good time to take stock of where China is
"at" by looking at some of the economic fundamentals.
Is China's economic
growth really in peril? A special issue of NIESR's Review tackles this
question. The answer appears to be, “no,
such alarmist talk is not justified”. Five articles examine drivers of China ’s growth,
the integration of its financial markets with those of the rest of the world,
inflationary pressures, the housing market, and cost competitiveness and
productivity trends across China ’s
regions.
The issue begins with an article by Linda Yueh, Director of
the China Growth Centre at the University of Oxford. She describes the
difficulties analysts face in trying to account for China's phenomenal growth
using standard growth models. The paper reviews the main modelling approaches
to growth, reviews the existing literature on China's growth, and decomposes
the factors behind China's growth into its various components. She points to three
issues that are salient. First, China is seemingly paradoxical in achieving
such growth with what appear to be weak institutions. In fact, as the paper
explains, China has engineered incentives for growth and productivity, albeit
in an unorthodox fashion, which have delivered very substantial economic
benefits. Second, China's impact on the global economy is so large that its
development is hard to comprehend within the confines of models which have
traditionally examined countries which are much smaller and, if larger, less
open to the international economy. Analysts may do well to think in terms of
what China is doing to the rest of the global economy, rather than begin with
questions about the effect of the global economy on China. Third, whilst questions
are frequently raised about the sustainability of China's growth trajectory the
paper points to the importance of one-off hikes in productivity arising from
various experiments China has undertaken with respect to capital restructuring
and labour market reform. But these
"one-off" episodes appear to happen quite regularly.
One crucial driver of China's economic growth has been the
rise of its public listed corporations. Back in 2001 the public listed sector
accounted for 14 per cent of China’s GDP. However, over the decade to 2010 the
total output of the public listed sector increased eleven-fold such that, by
2010, it accounted for 43 per cent of China's GDP (Bryson et al., 2012). Today
China's stock market capitalisation as a percentage of GDP is on a par with the
United States and greater than that in the Euro Area and Japan. One way to
assess China's role in the global economy is to examine the degree to which
China's stock markets (Shanghai and Shenzhen) are integrated with those
elsewhere. As Jan Babecky and co-authors explain in their paper dealing with
this issue, the existing literature is large but evidence on integration is
mixed. The authors have a lot of data to play with because, as they point out,
although the total number of listed firms in China is smaller than the United
States, Japan and the Euro Area, the total value of stock traded in China has
surpassed that in the Eurozone and Japan.
The authors consider stock price movements in China, Russia, the Euro
Area, Japan and the United States. Overall they find increasing stock market
integration after the 1997 Asian financial crisis and the 1998 Russian
financial crisis. Since then the speed with which differences in individual
stock market returns are eliminated after shocks (beta-convergence) has been
fairly constant. This is true for China, the Euro Area, Japan, the United
States and Russia. There has been no clear convergence, however, with respect
to cross-sectional dispersion in the returns on individual stock markets at a
given moment in time.
A perennial danger to growing economies is the threat of
inflation. This is particularly relevant for developing countries like China
where rapidly rising demand for goods and services has the potential to
outstrip their supply, at least temporarily. The Special Issue contains two
papers analysing inflationary pressures in China. The first, by Christian
Dreger and Yanqun Zhang, is a very interesting investigation into the sources
of pressure on consumer price inflation. The authors show that pre-Crisis
inflation in China was driven entirely by international factors such as food
and energy prices. But this changed with
the Crisis: since then domestic factors such as nominal wages have become
increasingly important. The paper points to important policy challenges ahead
for China. Growth in domestic demand is
a precondition for strong growth in the next Five Year Plan, and this in turn
relies on growth in real wages. To avoid inflation, it is going to be necessary
for productivity growth to match wage growth.
Of course, as the authors note, tight trade linkages and the role of
Chinese firms in international production chains mean that how this plays out
is going to affect all of us, not just the Chinese.
The second paper on price inflation by Xi Chen and Michael
Funk considers the potential for a house price bubble in China. The authors
deploy a recently developed methodology for identifying potential speculative
bubbles in real time, an approach that may assist in constructing early warning
systems in future. Although there has been a phenomenal real estate boom in the
2000s, one which received a boost from China's 2009 fiscal stimulus package, it
appears that house prices are not significantly disconnected from fundamentals.
A bubble in the period 2009-10 appears to have disappeared, in part due to
"cooling down" policy measures.
In general, then, there is little evidence of a speculative house price
bubble, although the authors remain cautious about potential developments in coastal
areas of China.
The final paper in the Special Issue by Lili Kang and Fei
Peng examines trends in productivity growth and labour costs in China. These are fundamental to China's economic
prospects. If you examine a league table of productivity levels across
countries you will see that the leading economies are the United States,
Germany and some of the other highly developed western economies. If China is
to be a top player globally it needs to foster very substantial productivity
growth. This entails fundamental
transformation of the Chinese economy, away from exporting cheap goods and
towards being a producer of high value-added goods, often for consumption by an
increasingly sophisticated domestic market. The implication is that it may not
be enough for China to be the place where the world's Apple products (and, more
recently, Land Rovers) are made. Instead, China will be looking to shift
towards the Silicon Valley end of the production chain where ideas are spawned
and innovation is key. What is often overlooked
in such debates is the degree of heterogeneity there is in the cost
competitiveness and productivity of China's regions. Kang and Peng examine
trends in unit labour costs across China's regions over a 35-year period for
nine single-digit industries. What they
find is a remarkable improvement in the
relative competitive position of the Interior as measured by declining relative
unit labour costs, such that its level of unit labour costs is now on a par
with the Coastal region, which is renowned as the most dynamic region in terms
of productivity. There has been relative stability over the whole period in
competitiveness of the West and Coastal regions, with the West having by far
the highest levels of labour costs. When drilling down to a more disaggregated
level, it is apparent that there is very substantial heterogeneity with respect
to trends in both labour costs and labour productivity across industry and
region. But, in general, the Interior,
the West and the Northeastern regions improved their competitive position
relative to the Coastal region, primarily through lower relative labour costs
than through productivity growth, though the latter were apparent in a sub-set
of industries. One might argue that convergence of this nature is good news for
China, since it implies a more efficient economy beyond the Coastal region, one
which should, in the long run, be better equipped to generate the goods and
services that the burgeoning middle classes will demand.
Taken together these papers give a fascinating glimpse
inside China's economy. The precise path
that China's economic development will take may be uncertain, but there is no
doubt that debate over that path, and its implications for the global economy,
will attract an ever-increasing number of economists studying China.
The following articles are contained in the February 2013 issue of the National Institute Economic Review:
Introduction
by Alex Bryson (NIESR)
What drives China ’s growth?
by Linda Yueh (St Edmund
Hall, University
of Oxford )
Convergence of returns on Chinese and
Russian stock markets with world markets:
national and sectoral perspectives
national and sectoral perspectives
by Jan Babecký (Czech
National Bank), Luboš Komárek (Czech National Bank,
Technical University Ostrava and University of Finance and Administration, Prague) and Zlatuše Komárková (Czech National Bank and University of Finance and Administration, Prague)
Technical University Ostrava and University of Finance and Administration, Prague) and Zlatuše Komárková (Czech National Bank and University of Finance and Administration, Prague)
Inflation in China
increasingly driven by domestic factors
by Christian Dreger (German
Institute for Economic Research, Berlin ,
and European
University Viadrina
Frankfurt Oder ) and Zanqun Zang (Chinese Academy of Social
Sciences , Beijing )
Sciences
Real-time
warning signs of emerging and collapsing Chinese house price bubbles
by Xi Chen (Hamburg University ) and Michael Funke (Hamburg University and CESifo, Munich University )
Cost
competitiveness comparisons and convergence in China
by Lili Kang (Tsinghua University ) and Fei Peng (University of Birmingham )
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: only a member of this blog may post a comment.