I have been writing quite a lot about immigration recently - here and here. But there’s an unfortunate tendency for dialogues on this topic (oral or in response to my columns) to go something like this: I, or other economists who work in this area, say that the empirical evidence suggests that immigration has little or no impact on employment or unemployment overall. A respondent points to an example – they personally, or someone they know, has lost out on an employment opportunity to an immigrant. Or they note that a particular local business or sector seems to employ mostly immigrants – Pret a Manger in London is a frequent target. We respond, saying that this is “anecdotal evidence”, sometimes (although I try not to use this phrase too much) referring to the lump of labour fallacy, and explaining again what the evidence says about overall or average impact. The respondent then concludes, perhaps understandably, that economists live in a statistical world which has little or no connection with reality; and worse, that when confronted with reality they are not interested.
I’d like to try to explain why “anecdotal evidence”, in this specific context, is indeed irrelevant, not because it’s anecdotal, but because it is a partial rather than general equilibrium concept. That is, by definition, it tells you only the local or partial impact of something, which may or not be offset by developments elsewhere in the economy, which – by definition – the anecdote cannot tell you anything about.
To illustrate this I think it’s helpful to look at a different example; not immigration, but inflation. Suppose that the price of chocolate goes up, as it is doing now, because of bad weather in the Ivory Coast. Now, what can we say about the impact on overall inflation:
- in the short term, consumers will adjust. They may buy less chocolate and more of other things;
- and, over time, so will other variables. The exchange rate may fall slightly (our terms of trade have worsened);
- and the Bank of England will adjust interest rates to ensure that we hit the inflation target.
Most economists will therefore agree on the following points:.
- there may be some impact on inflation in the short-term. This will be less than one might expect just from the price rise, and the magnitude and persistence of the impact will depend on how the adjustment process works;
- there will be no impact at all on inflation in the medium to long term.
Now suppose you want to know how quick the adjustment is – does the adjustment take a week or a year? This is an empirical question and you need empirical evidence; and there are various ways you might think about finding that evidence. But the key point here is that the fact you're paying more for chocolate doesn't tell you anything about the answer to this question - the impact on inflation overall in the economy. It is not just that the price of chocolate it is “anecdotal evidence”; it is that the anecdotal evidence about chocolate tells you absolutely nothing about the question you are actually interested in, which is about the speed of the adjustment process in the wider economy.
The interesting, and difficult question, is not what happens in chocolate shops, but in all shops, for all prices. The adjustment could take a week or a year, but looking at the price of chocolate alone - no matter how many shops you go into – can’t tell you. This is because inflation is a general equilibrium concept; it is determined by the overall levels of demand and supply in the economy, and looking at one price – a partial equilibrium concept - can’t tell you anything.
The same is true for immigration and employment. Theoretically, it is quite possible that sandwich shops hiring immigrants increases unemployment for Britons in the short term, and it is equally possible that it doesn’t. But the point is that whether it does depends not on what you observe in the shops themselves, but what is happening in the wider economy. The number of Britons employed in sandwich shops is a partial equilibrium concept, but the number employed overall – which depends not on sandwich shops, but overall levels of labour supply and labour demand – is a general equilibrium one. So we need to know what happens to the Britons who are not employed in the shops, and what happens to overall levels of wages and of consumer demand. Those are the factors that will determine the impact on unemployment. No matter how many sandwich shops you go into, and how many “anecdotes” you accumulate about Poles working there, that tells you – literally - nothing about the question that you are actually interested in.
So the point is not that anecdotal evidence is always invalid or irrelevant, or that it is not quantitative; it can often be very useful. Going into sandwich shops and talking to management and employees about how the industry is organised can tell you a lot about the employment practices of that specific industry; and indeed NIESR publishes numerous high quality research studies that use systematic and structured qualitative methods to do exactly this type of research. It is silly for economists to dismiss all evidence that doesn’t have numbers attached to it. But, when looking at economy-wide variables – inflation, unemployment - there is simply no alternative to looking at developments in the economy as a whole.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: only a member of this blog may post a comment.